Ducking, Dodging And Dawdling—-The Fed Misses Its Window For Hiking Rates

During the last year, the Federal Reserve has hinted that the period of “ultra accommodative monetary policy” was coming to an end. The Fed started that process last October by terminating the latest “Quantitative Easing” program which induced massive amounts of liquidity into the financial markets. Subsequently, the Fed has turned its focus towards the near ZERO level of the “Fed Funds” rate.

Over the last several FOMC meetings, Chairwoman Janet Yellen has hinted on numerous occasions that the Fed will begin increasing the overnight lending rate sometime in 2015. She has been adamant that the Federal Reserve has been “watching the data” closely to determine the appropriate timing of those increases. Not surprisingly, Wall Street has also been singularly focused on this issue. The increase in lending rates is the final step in ending the extremely long period of “accommodative policy” measures that has been a primary support of asset prices.

The problem for the Fed, as I discussed recently, is that they may have already missed their best opportunity to begin increasing interest rates. To wit:

“While the Federal Reserve hopes that they can effectively raise interest rates without cratering economic growth, the problem is that the bond market may have already beaten them to the punch.

While I do not expect Treasury rates to rise very much, the increase in borrowing costs in an already weak economic environment has an almost immediate impact. The chart below shows the periods in history where Treasury rates have risen and the impact of subsequent rates of economic growth.”

Interest-Rates-GDP-Growth-061015

But it is not JUST interest rates that suggest that the best opportunity for the Fed to hike rates is likely behind them.

One of the important factors for continued economic expansion, and required to offset the drag caused by tighter monetary policy, is an increasing rate of wage growth to support an expansion in consumption. As shown in the chart below the correlation between wage growth and economic growth is very high. This relationship, of course, is not surprising given that the economy is almost 70% driven by consumption which is supported by wages.

Wages-GDP-070615

Given that relationship, the best time for the Federal Reserve to hike interest rates is when wage growth has bottomed and is beginning to increase. As stated, the increase in wage growth leads to higher consumption that offsets the drag created by tighter monetary policy. Unfortunately, for the Fed, that window has likely already passed.

Wages-Fedfunds-070315

Real employment is also an issue for the Federal Reserve’s ability to hike rates. Despite continued media headlines of an unemployment rate near 5%, the Fed has failed to lift rates. The question that should be asked is why?

If the economy were truly running near full employment, as the U-3 rate would suggest, then the Fed should be aggressively hiking rates. The reason for the hesitancy is due to the continued “slack” in the labor force. That “slack” can be seen in the extremely low historical levels of labor force participation of the prime 25-54 age groups which is at the lowest rate since the late-80’s.

Employment-25-54-070615

The importance of this particular age group is that they are primarily responsible for household formations which supports stronger economic growth. Of course, lower employment rates, suppressed wages, and high indebtedness has made homeownership less of a reality for most. The issue of a “renter nation” is that it does not have the same economic multiplier effect that home ownership has created previously.

Housing-NationOfRenters-2-052015

Furthermore, the structural shift in employment, which has suppressed wage growth, continues to impede the ability of the economy to gain substantially stronger traction. As discussed recently at ZeroHedge, since the end of the last recession the number of “waiters and bartenders” replaced the lost manufacturing jobs. While “jobs” have indeed been created, there is a huge difference between “quantity” and “quality” when it comes to economic growth.

Zero-Hedge-070615

Lastly, the Federal Reserve’s ongoing interventions, as was their intention, inflated asset prices and boosted consumer confidence. However, the Fed should have utilized that strong momentum and relative complacency in the markets as cover for beginning their interest rate increases. Instead, they allowed the markets to over-inflate and now run the risk, when combined with increasing global risks like Greece and China, of “deflating” asset prices too quickly this late in the market cycle.

Fed-Funds-Crisis-061015

For the Federal Reserve, the issue of tightening monetary policy at a point when employment and economic growth remain weak, can have an exacerbated effect. Historically, when the Fed has entered into an interest rate hiking cycle, the economy has been at much stronger growth rates. As I discussed previously:

“There have only been TWO previous points in history where real economic growth was close to 2% at the time of the first quarterly rate hike – 1948 and 1980. In 1948, the recession occurred ONE-quarter later and THREE-quarters following the first hike in 1980.

The importance of this reflects the point made previously, the Federal Reserve lifts interest rates to slow economic growth and quell inflationary pressures. There is currently little evidence of inflationary pressures outside of financial asset prices, and economic growth is weak to say the least.

Therefore, rather than lifting rates when average real economic growth was at 3%, the Fed will not start this process at less that half that rate.”

Fed-Rates-Vs-GDP-Table-050515 Think about it this way. If it has historically taken 11 quarters to go fall from an economic growth rate of 3% into recession, then it will take just 1/3rd of that time at a rate of 1%, or 3-4 quarters. This is historically consistent with previous economic cycles, as shown in the table to the left, that suggests there is much less wiggle room between the first rate hike and the next recession than currently believed.”

The Federal Reserve has a very difficult challenge ahead of them with very few options. While increasing interest rates may not “initially” impact asset prices or the economy, it is a far different story to suggest that they won’t. In fact, there have been absolutely ZERO times in history that the Federal Reserve has began an interest rate hiking campaign that has not eventually led to a negative outcome.

While the Federal Reserve clearly should not raise rates in the current environment, there is a possibility they will anyway

The Fed understands that economic cycles do not last forever, and we are closer to the next recession than not. While raising rates would likely accelerate a potential recession and a significant market correction, from the Fed’s perspective it might be the ‘lesser of two evils. Being caught at the “zero bound” at the onset of a recession leaves few options for the Federal Reserve to stabilize an economic decline. The problem is that they may have missed their window to get there.